Abstract
The paper gives a brief presentation of the reconsideration of the neoclassical individual demand theory, which has occurred to be an inappropriate basis for constructing a collective market demand theory of practical interest. As consequences of this failure, the equilibrium theory created on this reductionistic basis does not reflect economic reality; and the theoretically developed economic approach to indexology is intended in statistical practice and other authors' literature for individuals or households. In the presented reconsideration of the reductionistic IDTh, the study's object is the "statistical ensemble of consumers" of a market observed through trade statistics. This ensemble's rationality is not an axiom, but a hypothesis being verified by the market statistics. These differences correspond to the general scientific character of our reconsideration of neoclassical individual demand theory, namely: objectivity, provability, and verifiability of facts. The rich mathematical and model apparatus of the IDTh has been conserved under the reconsideration. The obtained MDTh provides the economic legitimacy of the holistic equilibrium theory laid down by the works of Gustav Cassel and Abraham Wald, but until now rejected as a scientific direction of economic theory, as well as the "economic" approach in indexology, founded by Konüs, which takes into account consumer preferences to construct market demand's indexes.
Keywords:
Introduction
The problem of Economics scientization
Contemporary neoclassical Economics refers to the Social Sciences (Humanities) with their methodology, which is the methodological individualism, and it is more normative than positive methodology, accepted in the Natural Sciences. Within the framework of this methodology, it turned out possible to create only the individual consumer’s demand theory (IDTh), significantly developed mathematically, but impossible to create a collective market demand theory (MDTh) of practical and theoretical interest. The MDTh, adequate to reality, is necessary for the development of equilibrium theory, as a theory of prices that are usually set on markets in stable conditions; and for practical economic analysis. Besides, the equilibrium prices, which depend on the economy's technological and other characteristics, provide its efficacy and competitiveness in the world economy.
Undoubtedly, economic phenomena and processes are specific because their elements are people with the psyche, and their behavior is irregular and often spontaneous. However, for a long time, many authoritative economists believed that Economics, as a cognitive and practical discipline dealing with quantitative measures, primarily prices and quantities of obviously interrelated goods, should satisfy general scientific principles:
The scientization of Economics was systematically started by the founders of the neoclassical approach to this discipline, primarily by Stanley Jevons and Leon Walras. They both independently began to revise the conglomerate of economic theories that existed at that time, on the scientific principles laid down in the very developed by that time Physics and Mechanics. However, Jevons and Walras limited themselves mainly to the mathematical formalization of basic economic phenomena, which would provide provability of corresponding theories. Their seminal "Political Economies" founded the mathematical demand theory of
The process of Economics scientization has a rather hard history. It was accelerated by creating the Econometric Society in 1930 by some well-known economists, primarily by Ragnar Frisch as well as Irving Fisher, the first president of the society. Frisch, introducing the notion “Econometrics” in his 1930 Yale lecture has defined it as the synthesis of Economic Theory, Mathematics, and Statistics to turn the Economic Theory '
The current state and failures of the IDTh
The current state of the neoclassical IDTh is presented in the popular microeconomics textbook (Mas-Colell et al., 2001, Chs 1-4) and the recent textbook (Mandy, 2017, Part. 3). The former book describes comprehensively, without avoiding failures, two approaches to mathematical modeling an individual consumer's rational behavior regarding the choice from the attainable set of goods:
) cited in papers (Gorbunov & Lvov, 2019; Gorbunov et al., 2020).
Due to Economics’ failure, many authors fulfil their researches on the demand theory within the framework of neoclassical microeconomics in behavioural economics; see, for example, (Dannenberg & Estola, 2018; Hlouskova et al., 2019). And despite this failure, Kennet Arrow and Gerard Debreu (1954) modified the Walras' equilibrium model on the reductionistic base with two sets of agents: firms-producers and consumers, each of them acted independently and rationally following their individual goals. The authors proved the existence of equilibrium prices, and this paper became the seminal one for the mainstream direction of contemporary Economics. However, within this model's framework, it appeared impossible to prove the uniqueness of the equilibrium except some unrealistic assumptions concerning individual preferences. Moreover, in this model, the typicality of the equilibrium sets' pathologies was revealed (Mas-Colell et al., 2001, Section 17. E, Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem).
So, the Gorman-Samuelson “impossibility result” revealed that the reductionistic approach to creating a market demand theory (MDTh) that reflects reality is an inappropriate means, and such a theory is absent in neoclassical Economics so far. This is a fundamental failure of Economics for economic practice and for resolving the main economic theoretical question, which is the Value Theory in positive setting. More about these failures can be read in recent works (Coyle, 2019; Chorafakis, 2020; Estola, 2017; Móczár, 2018; 2020). Matti Estola believes that microeconomics' main failure is the absence of a dynamic theory of consumer demand, firm behavior, and goods markets. Correspondingly, the book of Estola is destined to the dynamization of microeconomics. But he rests in the reductionistic methodology, and it does not allow constructing an MDTh reflecting reality and being verifiable. Diane Coyle examines the Economics’ central figure Homo Economicus as a rational, self-interested person maximising the utility/profit and concludes that Economics must urgently revisit welfare economics. George Chorafakis (2020) claims that: “
Despite the failures of the reductionistic Arrow-Debreu equilibrium model, representing an artificial unrealistic economy, many mathematicians still continue to investigate possible pathologies of equilibrium sets (Balasko, 2016) and algorithmize equilibrium calculations (Nesterov & Shikhman, 2018). There are many attempts to use this equilibrium model as a basis for applied equilibrium analysis, and a recent book introducing this trend is (Cardenete et al., 2017). The authors declare that their equilibrium models presented in the book are an extension of the Arrow-Debreu model. However, their 'skeleton model' (Chap. 3) is essentially similar to the holistic Cassel-Wald model (Wald, 1951), discussed in the next subsection, with a multy-sector (non multy-firms) manufacturing sector and aggregated (market) demand with a priori imposed rationality condition.
Another consequence of the absence in Economics of an MDTh, reflected economic reality, is the blocking the theoretically developed economic approach to indexology, founded by the soviet mathematical economist Alexander Konüs. In statistical practice, this approach is blocked until now. In the international “Consumer Price Index Manual” (ILO, 2004) and in the literature of other authors, economic indexes are intended for individuals or households.
It is necessary to note the Werner Hildenbrand's book "Market Demand" (Hildenbrand, 2016). This and other works on modeling collective consumer behavior are constructed in a reductionistic way and assume information about households' consumption, which is a very restrictive (priory. See our review Zbl 1248.91034 on https://zbmath.org. Accessed 09/11/20.) .
Holistic approach to demand theory
The holistic approach to equilibrium theory was actually founded by Gustav Cassel, who reformulated the Walrasian equilibrium model by describing market demand as an initial object (Wald, 1951, p. 370). In the early 1930s, Abraham Wald (The cited 1951 paper is a translation of his German 1936 paper.) has investigated an improved Walras-Cassel equilibrium model and introduced an assumption of market demand; which coincided with the Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference suggested by Samuelson in 1938. With this condition, Wald has proved the existence and uniqueness of equilibrium, and it has called the
A holistic MDTh has been elaborated and approved in our Russian books and papers, since 2001, of which we note, due to the issue’s restrictions, only recent papers (Gorbunov & Lvov, 2019; Gorbunov et al., 2020) where there are other references. Unlike the neoclassical IDTh, where Preference Relation (PR) is a primitive characteristic of an individual, in the holistic MDTh, PR is the primitive characteristic of the
Problem Statement
The paper considers the problem of failures of contemporary neoclassical Economics, which consists in the absence of the theory of consumer market demand and its consequences.
Research Questions
The paper's research question is the creation of the theory of consumer market demand on scientific principles, which are
Purpose of the Study
The study's purpose is the reconsideration of the neoclassical demand theory with the conservation of its mathematical and modeling apparatus by changing the axiomatic approach to constructing economic theories to the general scientific approach to investigating real objects or processes.
Research Methods
The research is based on economic-mathematical modeling, developing a holistic approach to market demand.
Findings
Market complexity denies reductionism
A possible explanation of the inconsistency between the individual and market demand theories in the contemporary neoclassical Economics is the imposition on isolated independent individuals the rationality principles formed by the founders (Cournot, Gossen, and Jevons) based on the analysis of the joint actions of many people, reflected in trade statistics. Another possible reason that Jevons and Walras began their revision of Economics from developing demand theories for an individual consumer was the often productivity of the reductionistic approach in the natural sciences in studying complex objects (Firstly, in theoretical physics, reductionism is a natural method, because the main problem here is the basic understanding laws of organizing and proceeding of the Material World. Another example is the molecular-kinetic theory of the explaining macroprocesses in continuous media. ) . But reductionism has limits as a research methodology in natural science and engineering, where it was revealed rather long ago that complex phenomena are not completely explained by the properties and mechanical movement of their elements. Quite often, in physical, biological, and other systems, new phenomena emerge that their parts do not have on their own with growing their complexity. In cybernetics, such a systemic property is called '
As a part of the economy, the market system is much more complicated than the systems studied in physics. Market elements are people with a psyche, and their behavior is irregular and often spontaneous. Besides, market behavior is essentially collective; people don’t have complete information about goods and prices in the market, and they are subject to mutual and external influences: traditions, fashion, mood, advertising. These features predetermine the failure of the reductionistic principles for describing the market.
Statistical ensemble of consumers
Our holistic alternative to the microeconomic reductionistic consumer's demand theory is based on replacing the initial object, an individual, by the studied market represented as a whole object through the trade statistics in a previous period. The collective demand is the sum of individual demands on the market, but buyers' sets on almost any market are not observed and changeable. People expend their money in different markets, and the real market process may seem chaotic. But when the market is not subject to strong shocks, trade statistics usually shows steady dynamics that makes it possible revealing objective patterns in the collective behavior of the market buyers. We define the changeable set of the market buyers in terms of the fuzzy sets’ theory by Lotfi Zadeh.
The notion “fuzzy set SEC” means that the SEC is a subset of some universal set
Unlike the neoclassical Economics, there are no axioms that people are rational and independent agents of the economy, knowing all about market prices and goods. The alternative assumption is that
The collective utility maximization problem
The current classical individualistic rationality principle of utility maximization in an abstract style (introduced by Gérard Debreu), is based on the notion of binary PR, denoted as
, that is defined on some consumption set
The possibility of the consumers’ choice is mainly determined by the goods’ prices p, which are also n-dimensional nonnegative vectors, and all buyers'
. (1)
When constructing a non-trivial demand theory, all prices are assumed to be positive, that is, (strict positive orthant). The extremal correspondence of problem (1), that is, the Market Demand Correspondence , represents the market’s collective rationality. Due to the compactness of the admissible set and the continuity of the objective function, this problem is solvable for any , and the correspondence is compactly defined.
Thus, all the demand’s characteristics and properties derived from the Utility Maximization Problem (1) presented in (Mas-Colell et al., 2001, Ch. 3) and in (Mandy, 2017, Ch. 10). are true for our MDTh. We can say that
Two of basic characteristics of the demand (1) are:
1) homogeneity of degree zero: ;
To construct a meaningful analytical theory of market demand, the PR must have additional properties to ensure the single-valuedness and continuous differentiability of correspondence which becomes the Walrasian (ordinary) market demand function with values
. (2)
In terms of utility functions, the continuous differentiability of demand function (2) will be ensured if the function that represents the PR is twice differentiable and strictly quasiconcave. In addition, to avoid technical difficulties that are superfluous for economic theory, model (2) is usually considered in the domain of positive (nondegenerate) solutions , which are of practical importance. In this regular positive case, problem (2) is being solved or analysed using the classical Lagrange multipliers method.
Inverse problem of the MDTh
The inverse problem of the market demand theory is the problem of model (2) statistical verification. It consists in constructing a collective utility function via trade statistics, consisting of a finite pries-quantities set on observing the studying market. Such functional problems of mathematical modeling, as a rule, are ill-posed problems. They may be inconsistent or have non-unique unstable solutions. An ill-posed problem should be regularized, that is, it should be approximated by a well-posed problem that has a unique and stable solution concerning the initial data. Regularization is fulfilled using additional information about solution and, if any, data errors.
In (Gorbunov & Lvov, 2019; Gorbunov et al., 2020), a regularization method for the MDTh inverse problem, based on our Relaxation-Penalty Method (cited there) within the framework of the non-parametric demand analysis of Afriat-Varian, is presented and approved. Here the role of additional information is played by Fisher's statistical consumer demand indexes. Three types of tasks for constructing indexes with characteristics of optimism (low price indexes and high quantity indexes), pessimism (vice versa) and objectivity are suggested. These tasks have explored on real food statistics. Herewith, the hypothesis of the existence of a collective utility function, which rationalizes these statistics, was confirmed. In other words, the MDTh has been verified on real data.
Conclusion
Simplifying the formalization of the studied object in science is inevitable. Finding effective simplification that provides non-trivial development of positive scientific knowledge about an object is a matter of art and intuition. The reductionistic approach, very approved in the natural sciences, to creating a market demand theory of practical interest, has turned out a blind alley.
Our paper presented a reconsideration of the neoclassical individual demand theory, significantly developed formally, with replacements: the initial object, which is an individual, – by the statistical ensemble of consumers of the market under study; and the rationality axioms for preferences – by the corresponding hypotheses. The MDTh has reconsidered on the scientific principles within the framework of the holistic methodology. It can be verified against real market statistics. Because of the boundedness of any scientific theory of infinitely complex reality, not every market should be non-trivial explained by any demand theory with acceptable precision. A demand theory would have the scientific character if many real markets presented by their trade statistics verified the theory. We have a lot of successive verifications of the presented MDTh. The verification problem deserves extended consideration, as well as the holistic equilibrium theory.
Acknowledgments
The reported work is supported by Russian Foundation for Basic Research, project No 19-010-00972].
References
- Arrow, K. J., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica, 22, 265-290.
- Bjerkholt, O., & Qin, D. (2010). Teaching economics as a science: The 1930 Yale lectures of Ragnar Frisch. Working Paper, Memorandum, 05. Oslo: University of Oslo. https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/47292/1/625339991.pdf
- Balasko, Y. (2016). Foundations of the Theory of General Equilibrium. 2nd ed. Hackensack, NJ: World Scientific.
- Cardenete, M. A., Guerra, A.-I., & Sancho, F. (2017). Applied general equilibrium. An introduction. 2nd ed. Berlin: Springer.
- Chorafakis, G. (2020). Emergence versus neoclassical reductions in economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 27(3), 240-262.
- Coyle, D. (2019). Homo Economicus, AIs, humans and rats: decision-making and economic welfare. Journal of Economic Methodology, 26(1), 2-12.
- Dannenberg, A. A., & Estola, M. (2018). Willingness to pay in the theory of a consumer. Hyperion International Journal of Econophysics & New Economy, 11(1), 49-70.
- Estola, M. (2017). Newtonian Microeconomics: A Dynamic Extension to Neoclassical Micro Theory. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.
- Frisch, R. (1992). Statics and dynamics in economic theory. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 3(2), 391-401. (Translated from the Norwegian paper of 1929).
- Frisch, R. (1970). From Utopian Theory to Practical Applications: The case of econometrics. Nobel Prize Lecture. Oslo: University of Oslo. https://www.nobelprize.org/uploads/2018/06/frisch-lecture-1.pdf
- Gorbunov, V. K., & Lvov, A. G. (2019). Obratnaya zadacha teorii rynochnogo sprosa i analiticheskiye indeksy sprosa [Inverse problem of the market demand theory and analytical indices of demand]. Middle Volga Mathematical Society Journal, 21(1), 89-110.
- Gorbunov, V. K., Kozlova, L. A., & Lvov, A. G. (2020). Postroyeniye analiticheskikh indeksov rynochnogo sprosa: variativnyy podkhod [The construction of analytical indexes of market demand: A variative approach]. Voprosy Statistiki, 27(3), 65-80.
- Hildenbrand, W. (2016). Market Demand: Theory and Empirical Evidence. Princeton: Princeton University Press. https://books.google.ru/books?id=sPOQjwEACAAJ&hl=ru&source=gbs_book_other_versions
- Hlouskova, J., Fortin, I., & Tsigaris, P. (2019). The consumption-investment decision of a prospect theory household: a two-period model with an endogenous second period reference level. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 85, 93-108.
- ILO (2004). Consumer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice. Geneva: International Labour Office. The International Labour Organization website: https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---dgreports/---stat/documents/presentation/wcms_331153.pdf
- Mandy, D. (2017). Producers, consumers, and partial equilibrium. Amsterdam: Elsevier/Academic Press.
- Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M., & Green, J. (2001). Microeconomic Theory. 2nd ed. New York: Oxford University Press.
- Móczár, J. (2018). János Kornai, and neoclassical versus institutional economics. Acta Oeconomica, 68(s1), 73-83. https://doi.org/10.1556/032.2018.68.S.6
- Móczár, J. (2020). The Arrow-Debreu model of general equilibrium and Kornai’s critique in the light of neoclassical Economics. Journal of Banking, Finance and Sustainable Development, 1, 42-68. http://www.collegepress.org.uk/view-online/
- Nesterov, Yu., & Shikhman, V. (2018). Computation of Fisher–Gale equilibrium by auction. Journal of the Operations Research Society of China, 6, 349-389.
- Wald, A. (1951). On some systems of equations of mathematical economics. Econometrica, 19, 368-403.
Copyright information
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License.
About this article
Publication Date
16 April 2021
Article Doi
eBook ISBN
978-1-80296-104-1
Publisher
European Publisher
Volume
105
Print ISBN (optional)
-
Edition Number
1st Edition
Pages
1-1250
Subjects
Sustainable Development, Socio-Economic Systems, Competitiveness, Economy of Region, Human Development
Cite this article as:
Gorbunov, V. (2021). The Holistic Theory Of The Consumer Market Demand. In E. Popov, V. Barkhatov, V. D. Pham, & D. Pletnev (Eds.), Competitiveness and the Development of Socio-Economic Systems, vol 105. European Proceedings of Social and Behavioural Sciences (pp. 476-485). European Publisher. https://doi.org/10.15405/epsbs.2021.04.52